Road user charging policy shelved
June 3, 2009
Transport secretary Geoff Hoon has told the Financial Times that Britain is “a long way short” of adopting a national system of road user charging, saying that he wanted to see evidence of the practicality of such schemes before pressing ahead.
The government first committed itself to road user charging in 2004, but little progress has been made since 1.7m people signed an online petition opposing the idea in 2007and plans for a local congestion charge in Manchester were overwhelmingly defeated in a local referendum.
Lobbying for road user charging
Twenty years ago when the Environmental Transport Association (ETA) was founded, its position that a transport policy without road-user charging was worthless was ridiculed by (nearly) all and sundry.
A spokesperson at the ETA said: “Everyone agrees that Britain needs a safe, reliable and high quality transport system. Where we differ is how that vision can be achieved. Whether we give greater emphases to cycling or more roads or extra public transport one thing is certain: we cannot do it without road user charging.”
“It is easy to assume the electorate will not buy into the idea but that doesn’t make it wrong. Politicians see the next election and do what is necessary to win it. What we need to do is find statesmen or women who can see a good policy and sell it to the people and because of such a stance go on to win the next election.”
What is road-user charging?
This charge is simply a method of charging the motorist for the use of the road. At present the use of the road network is free. A motorist driving an electric car pays no tax or charge for using the roads – no fuel tax because on petrol is used and no vehicle excise duty because electric vehicles are zero rated. But electric vehicles still use roads and roads are valuable. Indeed a motorist driving a standard family car pays around £900 a year not for using the roads but for having a vehicle and for using petrol – quite a different thing.
What would the motorist be paying for?
There are any number of aspects that a motorist could be charged for using a road: damage to the road surface (track charges); noise; speed of travel; producing noxious gases; producing climate change gases; and most importantly access or use of roads at busy times.
How would the motorist be charged?
There are many ways in which a motorist could be charged. A simple method would be a carnet or window sticker which gives the motorist access to certain roads, for example, all cars entering Switzerland have to pay for a carnet either before they enter via the internet or at the border. Tolls to cross bridges or use sections of motorways are commonly found across the world. These methods involve payment at toll booths laid across the road and often apply at any given time of day. Lorry drivers in Austria, Cheskia and Germany are tracked by satellite and charged per mile. Most people imagine a national British system would involve a satellite tracking process with drivers being sent a monthly statement of all their journeys. This is possible but not necessary. The charge in Stockholm is levied as a vehicle passes under a beacon in the road which reads the number plate. Drivers are sent a bill which must be paid within fourteen days.
In Britain we could use a system whereby the car, knowing where it was using its own global positioning device deducts an amount from an allocated mobile telephone. This system is the cheapest to introduce and means neither the government nor other members of the household need know where the driver has travelled.
Why is a transport policy without road-user charging doomed to fail?
Essentially because roads are free – and when anything is free we tend to over use them. In the case of roads this leads to congestion. Studies have shown that even if the alternative public transport were free, motorists would still choose to drive – and in towns and cities this causes congestion.
What is congestion?
We all have an idea of what congestion is but there is not a standard definition.
What are track charges?
These are charges to cover the cost of building and maintaining the road itself. At the moment roads are maintained (or at least supposed to be) by various levels of government depending on the type of road.
I’m worried about my own privacy
As well you might be. If you are worried about the national government knowing the location of your car – if you drive along a strategic route (a motorway or main ‘A’ road) they know already. Most of these roads have automatic number plate recognition – at present they only identify the number plate but soon they will be able to identify the driver so always smile when you see a camera or else wear mirror glasses.
Who will get the money?
This is a vital issue. At the moment road-user charges in Britain are collected by the Highways agency for the tolls on bridges and by the county of London and the city of Durham in the case of congestion charges. The proposed congestion tax in the Manchester conurbation will be collected by the local transport executive. In future there could be many different organisations collecting the charge depending on where you are driving. There would be no harm in our paying the national government when on a motorway, the county government when on a main road and the town or city government when on a local road.
What will it be spent on?
In theory the road-user charge could be spend on anything. It could go directly into the general taxation pool or onto specific projects. It could depend on the criterion used for the charge. If it were noise then it could go to noise abatement; if it were track charges then it could go on improving the roads.
But I do not trust government to spend it on transport
Nor do I, so that is why the ETA recommended to government many years ago that a statutory regulatory authority, to be known as Oftrans be set up as a watchdog over all aspects of road-user charging in the country. Its board members being appointed sequentially for terms longer than a normal government term to avoid party political pressure.
Will the charge be accurate?
No, nothing is perfect. But accuracy is very important. If there were 1% lack of accuracy many millions of people would be affected. However, systems have been already developed across the world that have 0.0001 error rate or less. With the installation of Galileo global positioning the type of billing could be very accurate indeed.
Isn’t this a stealth tax?
Chancellors of the Exchequer, like every finance minister in the world would like to raise taxes without people noticing. That inclination does not change.
Why another tax?
The need for taxation and setting charges changes over time. The biggest challenge facing the user of transport today is congestion on our roads and poor quality of our public transport. Apart from raising revenue for government, fuel duty and vehicle excise duty do not help solve this problem. The ETA proposes that road-user charging should only be introduced on the basis that fuel duty and vehicle excise duty be withdrawn. So it would not be an extra tax but one less tax.
Will anyone save money?
It is likely that most people will save money. However, before we introduce road-user changing we have to be clear about who wins and who loses. As we focus on the possible people who will lose we need to help them make changes in order that they too can gain.
How would it work?
Each vehicle – as part of it management system would know its location and the time. From its own on-board information it would be able to calculate how much the journey costs and it bill itself from its store of money. There would be a number of ways of topping up the car – most people would have the vehicle do it automatically via the mobile phone or other digital network. Manufacturers would be given plenty of time to integrate the technology into their new cars – many of which have most of the technology already. Depending on the lead time given – some cars will have to have a small box retrofitted.
What about the “big brother” eye in the sky?
Although satellite technology would be used it would be purely be for the car to locate itself. Many cars have this functionality already. Government would have no greater knowledge of your whereabouts than they currently do from your mobile telephone.
Doesn’t this benefit the rich at the cost of the poor?
Road charging benefits everyone. Remember there will no longer be any fuel duty or vehicle excise duty. Most roads most of the time have no congestion. Most people will either pay the same or pay less. Those who pay more are those who put a very high value on time – business people attending a meeting or logistic companies making deliveries. They would be pleased that with clear roads they could arrive on time. Bus passengers would get the feeling that every road had a bus lane because the roads were clear.
Won’t people be able to avoid paying?
One needs to ensure that as far as possible no-one may avoid the charge. Some taxes are easier to avoid than others. Many people avoid income tax and VAT by taking cash in hand. In this country it is very difficult to avoid paying fuel duty but more lorries are managing to do so.
But it is possible that many people would try to avoid paying their appropriate road-user charge?
It is likely that it would be the same people who attempt to avoid paying their motor insurance and vehicle excise duty today. There are a number of ways for government to deal with the no payers.
What is the point of introducing complicated and unfair road pricing, when the simple answer is to reduce vehicle excise duty (road tax) and impose higher fuel taxes?
If one wants to deal with climate change alone then there is no point in introducing road user charging. In taxation terms, the most effective way to deal with climate change would be to extend the climate change levy on to fuel and call it a carbon tax. At the same time (best done gently) removing both fuel tax and vehicle excise duty. However, this assumes that road building and maintenance would come from general taxation. There are also other externalities of using road vehicles, like noise, road danger, noxious exhausts, which should be charged for.
Although road-user charge could be use for any purpose, it is more complicated and expensive to collect than a carbon tax or fuel duty so we would gain little on that front by its introduction. That is why road-user charging is best where other taxes would not work well: congestion is an excellent example. For instance, if a county only contained electric cars then there would be no fuel tax but the cars could be producing congestion. Increasing fuel tax would not ease congestion. Road-user charge is also very useful in paying for road maintenance.
Would road user charging benefit people living in rural areas?
The answer to this question depends on how the charge is applied and also on how the money raised is spent. If we make two assumptions: first, that the charge relates only to congestion and the cost of providing the roads; and, second, that the money raised is limited to the provision of transport services then the following is likely.
There is congestion in rural areas but it falls mainly on the national strategic highways: the M1 in Northamptonshire and the M6 in Staffordshire are good examples. In these places there will be pressure to use the road user charge to expand the roads to ease congestion. This could be done in a number of ways: to add extra lanes to the roads themselves; to divide the highway into long haul carriageways and local carriageways; or, to provide new roads on new rotes to reduce the amount of traffic currently funnelled into the few motorways already in place. There is an argument to use the money to provide better rail infrastructure along these routes.
For the remainder of the rural areas congestion is either very low and localized or non-existent. With zero fuel and road tax (the ETA recommends a general carbon tax) road travel costs in rural areas would plummet.
As urban areas would have a congestion charge, ranging from very low to quite high, this would, over time, displace travel from urban areas to rural areas. There would be pressure to develop business and residential districts in areas that hitherto had been declining. This can be seen as a blessing to some who would see an increase in employment and a curse to others who would see a loss of tranquillity and peace. Land-use planning policy will have to be developed before congestion charging comes into place to cope with these new issues.
The charge would also reflect the cost of providing roads. Depending on the sophistication of the charge and how it is distributed many roads might not have sufficient funds to pay for them. (The ETA recommends that the charge is passed directly to the highway authority in each area – the county being responsible for inter-settlement or “B” roads and the parishes for the rest, “A” roads being the responsibility of the national governments). This is because many rural lanes have such low traffic that in order to maintain them the charge would have to be set quite high and it might choke off the little traffic there was on them. Parishes in, for example, the counties of Devon, Fermanagh, Highlands, Norfolk and Northumberland might decide to close many miles of unused roads.
There would be significant changes in traffic in rural areas, especially if the charging regime was based on pure market costs, that is why the ETA recommends that the charge is introduced early to enable it to applied gradually.
How would road-user charging enable the provision of a decent public transport in rural areas?
In rural areas under a road-user charging regime motoring costs would be much lower but not everyone could either afford or otherwise be able to use a car. If no changes were made to other transport or planning policies, traffic in rural areas would increase simply because the costs were lower. More people would drive, they would drive more often and their journeys would be longer. For those people who were able to drive but could not afford a car rural car clubs could be an option.
There would be a possibility for the county government to deliberately charge a high fee to enable the provision of a public transport system between all villages in their county. What level of service constitutes a decent level would be up to the electorate.
Rural areas differ widely from the very sparsely populated areas like western Northumberland to near suburban rural areas like south Surrey. There is little doubt that Surrey could afford to provide a comprehensive and frequent inter-village bus service funded in part by a road-user charge because it is a small, rich and populous county whereas Northumberland would find such a comprehensive service difficult to provide because it is large, relatively poor and sparsely populated.
What is the ETA?
The ETA provides cyclists with green breakdown cover and green insurance products. As well as encouraging responsible driving to reduce carbon, the ETA campaigns for sustainable transport.
Information correct at time of publication.